000 | 02985nam a22006377a 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
001 | G40925 | ||
003 | MX-TxCIM | ||
005 | 20211006073149.0 | ||
008 | 121211s ||||f| 0 p|p||0|| | | ||
040 | _aMX-TxCIM | ||
041 | 0 | _aEn | |
072 | 0 | _aE14*E10 | |
072 | 0 | _aE16 | |
082 | 0 | 4 |
_a338.1 _bINT 1988 No. 5 |
245 | 0 | 0 |
_aGovernment intervention in agriculture: _b Cause and effect |
260 |
_aAldershot (United Kingdom) : _bIAAE*Gower |
||
340 | _aPrinted | ||
490 |
_aIAAE Occasional Paper ; _vNo. 5 |
||
520 | _aSudan'. irrigated subsector is the largen in lub-Saharan Atria. Firming is practised under scheme?mandated rotation with highly centralized decision making. Under this system. labour is the major input for which the lenant has allocation flexibility both doring the season and cross the three crops grown, sorghum, cottom and groundnuts. This paper analyzes the risk attributes of the production technology and measures farmer's attitudes towards risk in the irrigation schemes of Sudan. Stochastic production functions are specified where risk increasing and risk reducing input effects are allowed. Single-equation and systems procedures are employed to estimate the parameters of the firs two moments of the distribution of crop yields. The analysis supports the existence of aggregate indices for weeding and harvesting labour for cotton and sorghum while the hypothesis of separability in hired and family labour is rejected. The form of labour contract for hired labour is found to have significant implications on its production risk effects. When hired labour is paid in cash, production risks increase, as is the case with cotton and sorghum. When sharecropping takes place, as in groundnuts, production risks decrease with increased labour use. Supply behaviour of the tenant farmers under production uncertainty is simulated using a farm programming model. | ||
546 | _aEnglish | ||
595 | _aCSC | ||
650 | 1 | 0 | _aAgricultural policies |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aArgentina |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aBangladesh |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aBrazil |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aCote d'ivoire |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aCredit |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aDominican republic |
650 | 1 | 7 |
_aEconomics _gAGROVOC _2 _91093 |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aExports |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aFood aid |
650 | 1 | 0 |
_aFood production _91116 |
650 | 1 | 0 |
_aFood production _91116 |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aGatt |
650 | 1 | 0 |
_aIndia _91156 |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aJapan |
650 | 1 | 0 |
_aKenya _91167 |
650 | 1 | 0 |
_aLess favoured areas _92560 |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aManihot esculenta |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aMarketing |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aMexico |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aPrice policies |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aRural development |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aSoybeans |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aSubsistence farming |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aTechnical progress |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aTrade agreements |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aTrade liberalization |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aTrade policies |
650 | 1 | 0 | _aWest Africa |
650 | 1 | 7 |
_aWheat _gAGROVOC _2 _91310 |
650 | 1 | 0 |
_91109 _aFarming systems _gAGROVOC |
700 | 1 |
_aBellamy, M., _eed. |
|
700 | 1 |
_aGreenshields, B., _eed. |
|
942 | _cBK | ||
999 |
_c52592 _d52592 |